Supplement for Third Class of
Progressive Capitalism
Copyright © 2022 Bruce W. Hauptli
A. Questions from
Last Class.
B. Elaboration on
“The Wealth of Nations:”
[xii-xiv, the 8th
paragraph of the Kindle’s Preface] the true source of “the wealth of a nation”
lies in the former, in the creativity and productivity of the nation’s people
and their productive interactions with each other.
It rests on the advances in science,
which teach us how we can discover the hidden truths of nature and use them to
advance technology. Further, it rests on
advances in understanding of social organization, discovered through reasoned
discourse, leading to institutions such as those broadly referred to as the
“rule of law, systems of checks and balance, and due process.”
[30, the 4th paragraph
of Chapter 1’s “A misshapen economy creates misshapen individuals and a
misshapen society” section] all individuals combine self-interest and
other-regarding (altruistic) behavior (as Smith himself noted), and the nature
of our economic and social system changes the balance between the two.
Cf. p. 238.
Stiglitz’ footnote to this
passage’ reference to Adam Smith reads: [270]: ‘especially in his
Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759),
which opens with the famous lines: “How selfish soever man may be supposed,
there are evidently some principles in his nature, which interest him in the
fortunes of others, and render their happiness necessary to him, though he
derives nothing from it, except the pleasure of seeing it.”
Chapter 1’s section titled “A misshapen economy creates
misshapen individuals and a misshapen society” provides a summary of sorts to
the first part of the book and to Stiglitz’ “political” and “economic” core
contentions.
C: Part II.
Reconstructing American Politics and Economics: The Way Forward
I’m tempted to re-title this part:
A Decent Life For All: Reclaiming
America, Restoring Democracy, and Restoring Our Economy
In Chapters 8, 9, and 10 proposes his “political” agenda
and “Economic agendas. In the in
the ensuing two Chapters he intends to
[179-180, 2nd
paragraph of Chapter 9] … flesh out an economic agenda—based on the principles
already outlined—that can restore growth and social justice and enable most
citizens to have the middle-class life to which they aspire.
All of this will only be possible if there is more collective action—a
greater role for government.
Properly defined, this greater role doesn’t constrain society, but rather
liberates it and the individuals within it, by allowing them to live up to their
potential. Further, by restraining
the power of some to harm others, government can free those who would otherwise
always have to be on their guard, always having to take protective measures.
Chapter 8 Restoring Democracy:
[160, final paragraph of introductory section of Chapter 8]
this chapter focuses on three critical areas: ensuring
fairness in voting,
maintaining an effective system of checks
and balances in government, and
reducing the power of money in politics.
In regard to
voting fairness, he contends
[162, 6th paragraph of
“Voting Reforms…” section] six reforms that could make a difference are (1)
voting on Sunday (or by mail or making voting day a holiday), (2) paying
individuals to come to the voting booth (or alternatively fining them for not
coming, as Australia does), (3) making it easier to register, (4) ending the
disenfranchisement of those who have served prison time, (5) ending
gerrymandering, and (6) ensuring a path to citizenship for the Dreamers—young
people who have grown up in the country and know no other home than the US.
These reforms are based on a simple set
of principles: every American citizen should vote, and every vote should count
equally.
Frankly, and I believe
unfortunately, he is probably at his most specific at this point in the three
chapters!
In regard to
maintaining an effective system of checks
and balances in government he recommends that:
[164, final paragraph of
Chapter’s “Preventing Abuses of Political Power…” section]… we need to
strengthen our systems of checks and balances and the role of our professional
civil services and our independent agencies.
We need to think more how we can maintain democratic accountability and,
at the same time, prevent politicization and enhance the professionalization,
efficiency, and efficacy of government.
He also believes we need to have
term limits for Supreme Court justices recommending that [167, final paragraph
of Chapter’s “The Judiciary” section] “the next Democratic administration should
formally propose such an amendment, and as a temporary measure, until the
amendment is passed and goes fully into effect, the number of positions in the
Court should be increased.”
Finally, in regard to
reducing the power of money in politics
he recommends that
[172, final paragraph of
Chapter’s “Curbing Campaign Spending” section] corporations should only be
allowed to make a political contribution with a vote of a supermajority of their
shareholders (say, two-thirds)—so it’s not just the voice of the CEO that’s
being heard. If shareholders want to
contribute on their own, that’s another matter—and that’s already well
regulated.
In the Chapter’s “Curtailing
Revolving Doors” section, without specifying details, Stiglitz maintains we need
norms and ethics to break down the revolving door between government work and
employment thereafter, and while discussing the roles of political parties and
movements, he offers no specific proposals.
Finally, he concludes this chapter regarding his “political
agenda” with the up-coming two chapter discussion of his economic agenda by
indicating they are inseparably intertwined:
[178-179, third and second to
last paragraphs in chapter 8] how do we break out of this equilibrium, this
vicious circle where economic inequality leads to political inequality that
maintains, preserves, and even augments economic inequality?
It can be done, but only if there is a countervailing power—sometimes
called “people power.” Large numbers of
truly engaged individuals, in movements such as those described above, with the
movements working in concert with each other, through a political party, can be
more important than money.
Interim Critical Comment:
Of course, while recent years have
had a number of progressive political movements involving “large numbers of
truly engaged individuals”—for example: the 2017 Women’s March, the Indivisible
Movement (2016-present), The Black Lives Matter movement (beginning in 2012 and
surging more recently—it really isn’t true, however, that they’ve “worked in
concert.” Moreover each of these
movements quickly generated active and large groups of engaged individuals who
may, in fact, more truly be described as “working in concert.”
Indeed in his first chapter Stiglitz draws attention to how wealthy
conservative families have used their political power to effect some of the vey
economic policies that he contends led us to lose our way:
[43, final two
paragraphs of Chapter 1’s “Inequality of Wealth” section] we described earlier
two key ways to become rich: create more wealth or grab more wealth from others.
In the case of wealth, there’s a third:
inherit it.
Many among the top—including the
Walton family (heir to the Walmart fortune) and the Koch brothers—had achieved
that success not by working hard but, at least in part, by the good luck of
large inheritances. Americans like to
think of wealth inequality here as being different from that in old Europe,
based on a landed aristocracy of a bygone era. But
we have been evolving into a twenty-first-century inherited plutocracy.
Stiglitz’
footnote to the mention of the Walton and Koch families reads as follows: “these
two families’ vast wealth (reportedly almost $175 billion for the Waltons, and
$120 for Charles and David Koch in 2018) is as large as the total wealth of a
staggeringly large proportion of Americans—as of 2016, the most recent year for
which a reliable comparison could be made, the Waltons and the Kochs held as
much as the total wealth of the bottom 50 percent.
Data for wealth distribution is based on
the Federal Reserve’s Survey of Consumer Finances 2016, removing consumer
durables. Wealth data for the Waltons
and Kochs comes from Forbes magazine.
Jane Mayer’s bestselling book
Dark Money: The Hidden History of the
Billionaires behind the Rise of the Radical Right (New York: Doubleday,
2016) documents the outsized influence of the Koch brothers on American
politics.”
It appears to me that as Stiglitz’
confronts the “inseparably intertwined” economic and political issues his
“progressive agenda” faces a funded well-organized and deeply coordinated
movement—one which arose from “one percenters,” but which they successfully
pitched to “large numbers of individuals.”
Of course he has to be well-aware of the challenge and difficulty which
his progressive agenda faces, and this is why he is proposing to meet the
challenge with “people power!”
Chapter 9 Restoring A Dynamic Economy With Jobs and
Opportunity For All:
Stiglitz maintains that in this and the next Chapter he
intends to
[178-179, 2nd
paragraph of Chapter 9] … flesh out an economic agenda—based on the principles
already outlined—that can restore growth and social justice and enable most
citizens to have the middle-class life to which they aspire.
All of this will only be possible if there is more collective action—a
greater role for government.
Properly defined, this greater role doesn’t constrain society, but rather
liberates it and the individuals within it, by allowing them to live up to their
potential. Further, by restraining
the power of some to harm others, government can free those who would otherwise
always have to be on their guard, always having to take protective measures.
According to him
[180, first paragraph of
Chapter’s “Growth and Productivity” section] economic growth depends on two
factors: growth in the size of the labor force, and increases in
productivity, output per hour. When
either one goes up, so does the output of the economy.
Of course, what matters is not just
growth in national output, but in living standards of ordinary Americans [Wealth
of Nations], and that requires not just increases in productivity, but that
ordinary citizens get a fair share of that increase.
The trouble in recent decades is that neither labor force participation
nor productivity have been doing well—and the benefits of what gains have
occurred have gone to the top.
In regard to
labor force growth he maintains that we need to accommodate older employees and
employees with children, and we need to make our workforce healthier.
In regard to
increases in productivity he maintains that there to be large public investments
in basic research, education systems that can support the advance of knowledge,
a facilitation of the transition to “a postindustrial economy, and more
attention to providing social protections:
[189, first paragraph of
Chapter’s “Social Protection” section] almost all advanced countries provide
social insurance to cover at least many of these risks.
Governments have become fairly
proficient in providing this insurance—transaction costs for the US Social
Security system are a fraction of those associated with comparable private
insurance. We need to recognize,
however, that there are large gaps in our system of social insurance, with many
important risks still not being covered either by markets or by government.
He discusses unemployment insurance and suggests
consideration of a Universal Basic Income deserves serious consideration.
While there are some experiments with this idea at the local levels,
however, it would seem as if a national program would be highly unlikely to be
adopted without extraordinary political change.
Then he goes on to discuss full employment, and fiscal and tax policy,
and the importance of life-work balance.
According to him in our current situation
[199, the final two paragraphs of
the Chapter’s “Restoring Opportunity and Social Justice” section] inequality is
created not just by the rules that affect the incomes individuals receive, but
also by those that govern how corporations can engage in exploitation.
Our financial system is designed to
increase inequality: those at the bottom pay high interest when they borrow but
get low interest rates when they put their money in the bank.
“Reforms” in the financial sector—such
as the abolition of limits on interest rates charged—have only made matters
worse. Too much of the increasingly
limited competition that remains in this sector is directed at how to exploit
the unwary.
There are many reforms that could lead to greater equality.
For instance, other policies to help
those at the bottom are increasing minimum wages, and providing wage subsidies
and an earned income tax credit, topping up what the private sector pays to the
level of a livable wage.
Finally the
Chapter discusses how wealth and advantage (and poverty and disadvantage have
passed from one generation to the next, and how taxation policies might help
address these problems:
[205-206, the first paragraph of
the chapter’s “Taxation” section] a progressive, fair, and efficient tax system
should be an important part of a dynamic and just society.
We’ve described the important activities
that government needs to undertake, including public education, health,
research, and infrastructure; running a good judicial system; and providing a
modicum of social protection. All of
this requires resources, meaning taxes. It
is only fair that those who have a greater capacity to pay—and who typically
gain more from our economy—contribute more. But
as was noted in chapter 2, those at the very top actually pay a lower tax rate
than those with lower incomes. In these
and other ways, matters have only grown worse in the last three decades—with the
2017 tax bill, with its increase in taxes on a majority of those in the middle
to finance tax cuts for corporations and billionaires, standing out as perhaps
the worst piece of tax legislation ever.
Here his “agenda” is relatively clear
and clearly controversial.
Between 2004 and 2008 I made some progress in Florida in advocating that
the Governor and Legislature delay their efforts to dismantle the state’s
intangible tax—a tax which largely affected the wealthy and which the state
eventually eliminated. It is my
belief that once a tax source dries up, it is very unlikely to be reinvigorated.
In Maine our former Governor wanted to eliminate the income tax (and is
campaigning now advocating this again.
The preferred strategy for those Stiglitz has been criticizing has been
to reduce taxation so as to starve the sorts of governmental programs Stiglitz
offers. On his issue, however,
Stiglitz is uncompromisingly progressive:
[208, final paragraph of the
chapter’s “Taxation” section] special interests will line up against each of
these taxes. I don’t want to pretend
that it will be politically easy. But,
politics aside, there should be no shortage of funds to ensure that America will
no longer be a rich country with poor people—that a middle-class life can be and
should be attained by all Americans.
Chapter 10 A Decent
Life for All:
Stiglitz begins the Chapter as follows:
a combination of markets, civil
society, and government regulations and programs like free public education
created the middle-class life with middle-class jobs of the last century—making
life for workers far better than the abject state they were in a century
earlier. But over the past forty years,
we seem to have taken our middle-class life for granted and grown complacent.
The result is that large fractions of
citizens are struggling to maintain that lifestyle, and for significant numbers,
it’s become unattainable. When wages for
very large parts of the country stagnate or decline over a period of a half a
century in the most prosperous large country in the world, it is clear that
something has gone wrong. The reforms
discussed in the previous chapter would go a long way toward ensuring that the
take-home pay of every worker is at least a livable wage in twenty-first-century
America. They also hold the prospect of
restoring sustainable growth. But they
won’t suffice to enable many Americans to have a decent, middle-class life.
Over recent decades, markets have not done a good job of ensuring the
basic requisites of a decent life for all. Some
of these failures are by now well understood: markets would prefer to insure
only the healthy, and they devote enormous resources to differentiating between
the healthy and others. But a society
where only the healthy can get insurance will not be a productive or healthy
society. So too, markets can do a good
job at providing education for children of the rich, but a society where only
the children of the rich get a good education is neither fair nor efficient.
Sometimes, conservatives say, these aspirations to correct market
failures and to overcome their limitations are well and good but they cost
money. It’s something we can’t afford
now, especially with our massive public debt. This
is sheer nonsense. Countries much poorer
than the US do a better job than we do in meeting these aspirations of their
citizens to health care and education for all and the other prerequisites of a
decent life. In fact, the United States
did a better job some sixty years ago. At
the end of World War II, we were much more indebted, and we were much poorer,
with a per capita income just a quarter of what it is today.
The chapter discusses four elements of “a decent life:”
health care for all, a decent retirement, home ownership, and education.
In each of these aspects of a decent life, he argues, the market has not
provided many Americans with a possibility of a decent life.
-in the case of health care
market-based plans are unaffordable for many while government funding has done a
better job but isn’t yet sufficiently broadly available,
-in the case of retirement
greater strides have been made, but proposals to privatize the system are
dangerous, and the talk of it as an “entitlement” ignores the fact that all pay
into it (and its future funding problems, I might add, are partially the result
of significant withdrawals from the Social Security Trust Fund by the Congress
for funding non-retirement expenses,[1]
-in the case of home ownership he
contends that the financial crises and the current public-private mortgage
system (which he contends leaves the private side with the profits while the
public side takes on the risks) has made mortgages too costly and potentially
removes this element of the decent life from far too many,
-in education he maintains higher
tuition and higher debt are fundamental problems I making educational
opportunities available to all.
In each case Stiglitz believes that that brad public
support can help restore the sort of broad enjoyment of a middle class life hat
was available for many in the 1950s.
In the Chapter’s “Conclusions” Section he maintains:
there are just a few things that
are at the core of a decent life: people care about jobs with fair pay and a
modicum of security both before and after retirement, about education for their
children, about owning a home, and about access to good health care.
In each of these areas capitalism
American-style has failed large swaths of our population.
We can do better.
The program outlined above is a
beginning. It cannot fully address some
of the deep-seated problems that have been festering since the era of Reagan.
We should have done something to help
those who were losing their jobs and whose skills were not up to the new
technologies. But we didn’t.
We should have had better health care
and education systems. But we didn’t.
We should have helped those cities that
were facing deindustrialization and the destruction of their community.
But we didn’t.
We are now paying the price for these
failures. We can’t redo history, and we
shouldn’t try to go back to the past. We
have to do the best we can, given the hand we’ve dealt ourselves.
The agenda I’ve laid out can be achieved within the financial constraints
facing the country today, making our families’ lives better and our economy
stronger. To those who say we can’t
afford it, I reply: we, as a rich country, can’t afford not to ensure that this
middle-class life is within the grasp of more of our citizens.
Another world is possible, and this progressive agenda can help us create
it.
Chapter 11
Reclaiming America:
In this Chapter Stiglitz talks about the disparity between
our values and our social reality.
He maintains that:
[223-224, 23rd
paragraph of Chapter’s “The Disparity…” section] the vessel of the country will
veer into dark seas, where the most vulnerable are left to fend for themselves,
rule-breakers are rewarded, regulators are effectively “captured” by those they
are supposed to regulate, watchdogs are cowed, economic gains accrue mainly to
those who are already rich, the result of exploitation rather than wealth
creation, and ideas like truth, facts, liberty, empathy, and rights are mere
rhetorical devices, employed when politically convenient.
As he sees it a significant factor behind the disparity
between our values and reality is our acceptance of the “myth of the self-made
individual.” It encourages the view
that governmental programs are unnecessary.
When combined with a deep conservatism when it comes to social and
economic change, the disparity becomes difficult for some to even detect, let
alone address. Then he further
elaborates our shared values and anxieties, and the problems created when public
institutions are undermined:
[240, the 5th
paragraph of the chapter’s “How we arrived at this juncture” section] we didn’t
understand the true foundations of our well-being—the increases in our standard
of living as well as the fulfillment of our highest ideals—rested on the
foundations of science, rational enquiry, and discourse, and the social
institutions derived from them, including the rule of law based on democratic
processes.
The internationalism and free markets of neoliberalism with its false
promises are now being replaced with primitive protectionism and nativism, whose
promise of restoring the United States to prosperity is even less likely to be
fulfilled. For an economist, it is easy
to attack the market fundamentalism/neoliberalism that came to dominate in the
years after Reagan. It was based on a
set of refutable (and refuted) hypotheses. But
at least one could have a rational discussion about neoliberalism, ascertaining
whether there is a grain of truth in some of the arguments and empirical
hypotheses. Not so for Trump, partly
because the underlying ideas (if they can be dignified with that term) are
inchoate. While in domestic policy he
champions the virtues of the market economy—even America’s rent-seeking
variant—in international trade he takes the opposite stance: he doesn’t believe
in unfettered competitive markets, but rather in power-based managed trade,
going back to discredited mercantilist ideas.
He summarizes some of the core political and economic
contentions we have covered, discusses our anxieties and despair, and then
contends that
[246-247, the first four
paragraphs of the chapter’s “Is there hope?” section] America’s history gives us
hope. But any student of the dark
history of authoritarianism and fascism in other countries knows this brighter
future is not inevitable.
As we’ve noted, America twice before pulled back from extremes of
inequality—after the Gilded Age and the Roaring 20s.
The challenge today, though, may be even
greater than then: there is perhaps even more inequality now, and with recent
Supreme Court decisions, money has more power in politics.
And modern technology can more
effectively translate disparities in money into disparities in political power.
Ultimately, today, the only countervailing power is people power, the
power of the voting booth. But the
greater the inequality of wealth and income, the harder it is for this
countervailing power to be exercised effectively.
That is why achieving greater equality
is not just a matter of morals or good economics; it is a matter of the survival
of our democracy.
With the agenda I’ve proposed, all Americans can attain the life to which
they aspire—in ways that are consonant with our values of choice, individual
responsibility and liberty. The agenda
is ambitious and yet necessary: as bad as things are today, there is a good
chance that, with the advances of technology that are already on the horizon,
they may get much worse—if we continue on our current course.
We may wind up with even more inequality
and an even more divided society, with even more discontent.
Incrementalist policies—a little more
education here, a little more assistance there—as important as they are as
components of an overall strategy, are not up to the challenges America faces
today. We need the dramatic change in
direction that this book’s progressive agenda calls for.
(end)
[1] According
to
Wikipedia: The Social Security
Administration collects payroll taxes and uses
the money collected to pay Old-Age, Survivors,
and Disability Insurance benefits by way of
trust funds. When
the program runs a surplus, the excess funds
increase the value of the Trust Fund.
As of
2021, the Trust Fund contained (or
alternatively, was owed) $2.908 trillion.
The Trust Fund is required by law to be
invested in non-marketable securities issued and
guaranteed by the "full faith and credit" of the
federal government.
These
securities earn a market rate of interest.
Excess funds are used by the government for
non-Social Security purposes, creating the
obligations to the Social Security
Administration and thus program recipients.
However,
Congress could cut these obligations by altering
the law. Trust
Fund obligations are considered
“intra-governmental” debt, a component of the
“public” or “national” debt.
As of
June 2015, the intragovernmental debt was $5.1
trillion of the $18.2 trillion national debt.
According to the Social Security Trustees, who
oversee the program and report on its financial
condition, program costs are expected to exceed
non-interest income from 2010 onward.
However,
due to interest (earned at a 3.6% rate in 2014)
the program will run an overall surplus that
adds to the fund through the end of 2019.
Under
current law, the securities in the Trust Fund
represent a legal obligation the government must
honor when program revenues are no longer
sufficient to fully fund benefit payments.
However,
when the Trust Fund is used to cover program
deficits in a given year, the Trust Fund balance
is reduced. One
projection scenario estimates that, by 2034, the
Trust Fund could be exhausted.
Thereafter,
payroll taxes are projected to only cover
approximately 76% of program obligations.
Social
Security Trust Fund - Wikipedia
accessed 01/28/22.
Go to Midcoast Senior College Webpage
File revised on 02/04/22