Supplement for Second Class of
Progressive Capitalism
Copyright © 2022 Bruce
W. Hauptli
A. Questions from Last Class:
B. Remaining From
and Elaborations on First Class:
Objective vs.
Social Facts:
In passing in the first class I noted that we musty
distinguish between subjective, intersubjective, and objective facts.
It is a subjective fact that I enjoy teaching—if my enjoyment changed,
this may cease to be factual. It is
an intersubjective fact (for those Zooming in here) that we value Midcoast
Senior College—were we, or it, to change, this might cease to be factual (though
others might continue to do so, so, for them, it would be continue to be the
case). It is an objective fact that
water freezes at 32° Fahrenheit at sea level—though this could cease to be the
case if there were requisite changes in the natural environment.
Amongst the
intersubjective sort of facts there are a whole category of social facts, and
the “economic facts” Stiglitz appeals
to are in this category. Some
social facts are legal in character
(the fact that we drive on the right side of the road, that Maine has an income
tax, that corporations have property rights,
etc.).
Some social facts arise because organizations (whether formal or
informal) adopt rules: that shots from beyond the arc in basketball earn three
points, that chess pieces may only move in determinate manners, that one should
keep one’s promises. Note that some
of these depend on one’s country (driving rule facts), while others apply across
borders (soccer and chess facts).
Some are of short duration (legal facts) and some remain unchanged for millennia
(chess rules). In the social
sciences there is an effort to identify very broad and pervasive facts:
psychologists endeavor to uncover broad truths about human (individual and
social) motivations, political theorists endeavor to find broad and pervasive
facts about political organizations, and economists try to do the same with
regard to economic systems.
We will need to discuss, in a future class, how differences
amongst rival theorists (and their “schools”) might best be addressed, but at
this point we need to first under and Stiglitz’ economic theory.
An important beginning point is highlighted in the discussion of his core
economic contentions.
For the final
class I want to encourage you to look at a piece on my website titled
“Relativism, Objectivism, and Judging” and two readings I ask those reading
the piece to do:
Readings: Ambrose
Beirce's "A Horseman In The Sky" and
Jonathan Bennett's "The
Conscience of Huckleberry Finn)".
Stiglitz’ Core Economic Contentions [see
First Class
Supplement which has been revised]
Stiglitz on “Why Government?” [see
First Class
Supplement which has been revised]
Discussion.
C. Losing Our Way:
Stiglitz contends that the divisiveness we now face is
evidenced by the fact that [p. xiii,
p. 2
of Preface on Course Webpage
in the first full paragraph] “not since before the Great
Depression have the country’s richest citizens captured such a large proportion
of the nation’s income.” He
believes that we face this divisiveness in large part because of our
[xiii,
p. 2
of Preface on Course Webpage
in the second full paragraph] …failure to handle well the
transition from a manufacturing economy to a service-sector economy, to tame the
financial sector, to properly manage globalization and its consequences, and
most importantly, to respond to the growing inequality, as we seemed to be
evolving into an economy and democracy of the 1 percent, for the 1 percent and
by the 1 percent.”
While I can appreciate his rhetorical flourish here, I don’t believe one can call an economy of the 1 percent, for the 1 percent and by the 1 percent a democracy! Nor do I believe we have such an economy—though, clearly, Stiglitz believes we have headed too far in this direction!
As he sees it,
[p. 24, the second paragraph of
Chapter 1’s section “Alternative Theories to the Sources of the Wealth of
Nations”] for markets to work well on their own, a host of conditions have to be
satisfied—there has to be robust competition, information has to be perfect, and
actions of one individual or firm can’t impose harm on others (there cannot, for
example, be pollution). In
practice, these conditions are never satisfied—often by a large measure—which
means that in these instances markets fail to deliver.
Before environmental regulations, our air was unbreathable and our water
undrinkable and unswimmable—and the same is true today in China, India, and
other countries where environmental regulations are too weak or too weakly
enforced.
[45-46, the second paragraph of
Chapter 1’s section “Conclusions”] The slogan “leave it to the market” never
made sense: one has to structure markets, and that entails politics.
Those on the Right grasped this, and beginning with Reagan, they
restructured markets to serve those at the top.
But they made four key mistakes: they didn’t understand the eviscerating
effects of ever larger inequality; they didn’t understand the importance of
long-term thinking; they didn’t understand the necessity of collective
action—the important role that government has to play in achieving equitable and
sustainable growth; and most importantly, they failed to understand the
importance of knowledge—even as we were championing ourselves as an innovation
economy—and that of basic research, the foundations on which our technology
rests. They thus downplayed key
factors that were essential to the success of capitalism over the past two
hundred and some years. The result
is largely what one should have expected: lower growth and more inequality.’
Topics to be addressed:
Chapter 1 Introduction:
[9, second paragraph chapter’s
“The Wealth of Nations” section] the true wealth of a nation is measured by its
capacity to deliver, in a sustainable way, high standards of living for all of
its citizens.
[10-11, fourth paragraph of the
chapter’s “The Enlightenment and its aftermath” section] the absence of royal or
ecclesiastical authority to dictate how society should be organized meant that
society itself had to figure it out. One
couldn’t rely on authority—either on Earth or above—to ensure that things worked
out well, or as well as they could. One
had to create systems of governance. Discovering
the social institutions that would ensure the well-being of society was a more
complicated matter than discovering the truths of nature.
In general, one couldn’t do controlled
experiments. A close study of past
experiences could be informative, however. One
had to rely on reasoning and discourse—recognizing that no individual had a
monopoly on our understandings of social organization.
Out of this reasoning came an
appreciation of the importance of the rule of law, due process, and systems of
checks and balances, supported by foundational values like justice for all and
individual liberty. Our system of
government, with its commitment to fair treatment of all, required ascertaining
the truth. With systems of good
governance in place, it is more likely that good and fair decisions are made.
They may not be perfect, but it is more
likely that they will be corrected when they are flawed.
Over time, a rich set of truth-telling,
truth-discovering, and truth-verification institutions evolved, and we owe to
them much of the success of our economy and our democracy.
Central among them is an active media.
Like all institutions, it is fallible;
but its investigations are part of our society’s overall system of checks and
balances, providing an important public good.
Discussion of sections on the
attacks on universities, science, the judiciary.
[25, the second to last paragraph
of the chapter’s “Alternative Theories to the Sources of the Wealth of Nations”
section] deregulation, especially of the financial market, brought us the
downturns of 1991, 2001, and most grievously, the Great Recession of 2008.
And lower taxes did not have the energizing effect that supply-siders
claimed.
Chapter 2 Toward A More Dismal
Economy:
[33] Figure 2
[36, third paragraph of chapter’s
“International comparisons in standards of living section] using the
Human Development Index, a
broad-gauge measure of standard of living, the US ranks thirteenth, just above
the United Kingdom. Once America’s
inequality is taken into account, it slips to twenty-fourth.
Discussion of “Growing
Inequality” in race, ethnicity, gender, health, wealth, and opportunity.
We covered pp. 45-46 [Chapter 2, second and final paragraphs of “Conclusions” section] above.
Chapter 3. Market Power and
Exploitation
[49, first paragraph of chapter’s
“The Big Picture section] market power allows firms to exploit consumers by
charging higher prices than they otherwise would and by taking advantage of
consumers in a variety of other ways. Higher
prices hurt workers just as much as lower wages.
In the absence of market power, the forces of competition would drive
excess profits to zero, but as we shall see, it is these excess profits that are
at the root of America’s growing inequality. Market
power also allows firms to exploit workers directly, by paying lower wages than
they would otherwise, and by taking advantage of labor in other ways.
Market power gets translated into
political power. The huge profits
generated by market power allow corporations—in our money-driven politics—to buy
influence that further enhances their power and profits, for instance by
weakening unions and the enforcement of competition policy, giving free rein to
banks to exploit ordinary citizens, and structuring globalization in ways that
further weakens workers’ bargaining power.
[51, first paragraph of chapter’s
“Market power and the division of the national pie” section] the laws of
economics are different from those of physics: markets are shaped by public
policy, and most markets are far from competitive.
Public policy shapes, in particular, who
has how much market power.
[70, second to last paragraph of
chapter’s “Curbing Market Power…” section] what is needed now is a change in
these presumptions, with their associated burdens of proof, based on the
hypothesis that markets are fundamentally competitive.
Anticompetitive practices—actions that
reduce competition in the market—should be presumed to be illegal, unless there
is strong evidence that (a) there are significant efficiency gains and that a
significant proportion of the benefits of these efficiency gains accrue to
others than the firm and (b) these efficiency gains could not be achieved in a
less anticompetitive manner. We discuss
a number of other changes in presumptions below.
Government will also have to be more active in resorting to a broader
range of tools, not just limiting mergers and enjoining certain anticompetitive
practices….Mergers that lead to major conflicts of interest should be prohibited
(as when an internet provider acquires a firm creating entertainment content),
and if they’ve already been allowed, there should again be divestiture.
Similarly, firms with market power
should be proscribed from entering business activities where there is a conflict
of interest with their existing customers.
Chapter 4 America At War With
Itself Over Globalization
[81, end of sixth paragraph of
introductory passages in the chapter] ... we mismanaged the consequences both of
globalization and of technological progress.
If we had managed these well, both could have generated the blessing that
their advocates claimed.
[97 final paragraph in chapter’s
“Globalization in a world with multiple value systems” section] we are now
confronting the reality that different countries will organize their economies
in fundamentally different ways, reflecting their values and beliefs.
Not everyone wants American-style capitalism, with its corporate power
and inequality. And certainly, not
everyone wants China’s level of intrusion in the economy or its lack of concern
for privacy. A values-free system of
unfettered globalization can’t work; but neither will a system in which the
rules of the game are dictated by one country or another.
We will have to find a new form of
globalization, based on some version of peaceful coexistence, recognizing that
even if we have markedly different economic systems, there are still large areas
where we can fruitfully engage in commerce. We
will need a minimal set of rules—some version of a rule of law, what might be
thought of as a basic set of rules of the road.
We can’t force others to adopt our regulatory system, nor should we be
forced to adopt theirs. And it will be a
lot better for all of us if these rules are global, multilateral, and can be
agreed upon by all countries.
Chapter 5. Finance and the
American Crisis
[113, first paragraph of
chapter’s “Conclusions” section] the financial sector exemplifies in so many
ways all that is wrong with our economy. The
sector has been the example par excellence of rent-seeking—the bankers increased
their wealth at the expense of the rest of society, in what clearly turned out
to be a negative sum game, where what the rest of society lost was far larger
than what the bankers gained. They
exploited the financially unsophisticated, but there is no honor among thieves:
they also exploited each other. The
economy was hurt in so many ways: resources that could have gone into wealth
creation were devoted to exploitation, as the financial sector grew and grew in
size, attracting some of the country’s most talented individuals.
But all the country had to show for it
was slower growth, more volatility, and greater inequality.
The financial sector illustrates too
what’s wrong with unfettered markets: bankers’ unbridled pursuit of their
self-interest didn’t lead to the well-being of society, but to the largest
financial crisis in 75 years.
Chapter 6 The Challenge of New
Technologies: whereas Chapters 2-5 provide Stiglitz’ account of where our
economy has gone wrong, this chapter raises the claim that mismanagement of
globalization is an additional cause of our malaise.
He devotes so much space to what might be done to better regulate new
technologies that this chapter could itself take a course to cover.
I am going to opt to skip discussion of it as there just isn‘t enough
time in this four week course to take it up.
D. Summation:
On p. 144, the sixth paragraph of Chapter 7’s “Regulation
and Writing the Rules of the Game” section Stiglitz contends
every society has learned the
painful way that there are those who seek to get rich not by inventing a better
product or making some other contribution to society, but by
exploitation—exploitation of market power, exploitation of imperfections of
information, exploitation especially of those who are vulnerable, poor, or less
educated. To take one classic
example: meatpackers tried to take advantage of consumers, selling them rotten
meat, until Upton Sinclair exposed this in his 1906 book,
The Jungle.
The book caused such furor that the industry then asked to be regulated
so confidence in meat could be restored.
I have not highlighted portions of Stiglitz’ discussion of
the “Gilded Age” and the "Roaring 20s," but
the reference to Sinclair’s novel is illustrative.
As Wikipedia notes,
The Jungle is a 1906 novel
by the American journalist and novelist Upton Sinclair (1878–1968).
The novel portrays the harsh conditions and exploited lives of
immigrants in the United States in Chicago and similar industrialized cities.
Sinclair's primary purpose in describing
the meat industry and its working conditions was to advance socialism in the
United States. However, most
readers were more concerned with several passages exposing health violations and
unsanitary practices in the American meat packing industry during the early 20th
century, which greatly contributed to a public outcry which led to reforms
including the Meat Inspection Act.
The book depicts working-class poverty, lack of social supports, harsh
and unpleasant living and working conditions, and hopelessness among many
workers. These elements are contrasted
with the deeply rooted corruption of people in power.
A review by the writer Jack London called it the “Uncle Tom's Cabin of wage
slavery.”
Sinclair was considered a muckraker, a journalist who exposed corruption
in government and business. In
1904, Sinclair had spent seven weeks gathering information while working
incognito in the meatpacking plants of the Chicago stockyards for the socialist
newspaper Appeal to Reason.
He first published the novel in serial
form in 1905 in the newspaper, and it was published as a book by
Doubleday in 1906.[1]
Describing the
response to the publication, Wikipedia
notes:
…Sinclair intended to expose “the
inferno of exploitation [of the typical American factory worker at the turn of
the 20th Century]’ but the reading public fixed on food safety as the
novel’s most pressing issue. Sinclair
admitted his celebrity arose “not because the public cared anything about the
workers, but simply because the public did not want to eat tubercular beef”
Sinclair's account of workers falling into rendering tanks and being
ground along with animal parts into "Durham's Pure Leaf Lard" gripped the
public. The poor working conditions, and
exploitation of children and women along with men, were taken to expose the
corruption in meat packing factories.
The British politician Winston Churchill praised the book in a review.
Public pressure led to the
passage of the Meat Inspection Act and the Pure Food and Drug Act; the latter
established the Bureau of Chemistry (in 1930 renamed as the Food and Drug
Administration).[2]
In many ways, Stiglitz’ is calling for the sort of change
which Sinclair’s work helped bring about, though, I believe, he doesn’t have
Sinclair’s socialist motivations.
Unlike Sinclair, Stiglitz would be happy with public policies which make
capitalism stronger. Ultimately he hopes for public policy and economic transformation akin to
those which led to the New Deal and the rise of the American Middle Class.
Next Time: Class III. A Decent Life For All: Reclaiming
America, Restoring Democracy, and Restoring Our Economy
[1]
Wikipedia,
The Jungle - Wikipedia, accessed on 01/19/22.
[2]
Ibid.
Go to Midcoast Senior College Webpage
File revised on 01/28/22